Thinking about at how New York City government works

Tag: budget

QUIS  CUSTODES?

Who Guards the Guardians?

            One lens through which New York City government in the 20th Century has been viewed is the decades long clash between elected officials who were products of political machines and self-styled “reformers” The classic discussion of this history is Sayre and Kaufman’s “Governing New York City: Politics in the Metropolis.” Today, there seem to be no reformers – no public voices who advocate for what they regard to be in the best interest of all New Yorkers. They have been replaced by advocates for particular communities and personal interests. How did that happen and is it important?

The machines were political operations built up from neighborhood organizations that whipped votes for their candidates in exchange for patronage and contracts. Jimmy Walker, William O’Dwyer, Robert Wagner and finally Abraham Beame were products of the city’s organization political clubs. The machines generally dealt in ethnic politics and rallied around Irish, Italian and Jewish candidates. The machines were regarded by reformers as corrupt, inefficient and exclusive – particularly excluding Black and Hispanics from power. The most famous reformer was, perhaps, Fiorello LaGuardia. Both John Lindsey and Ed Koch came up each through reform ranks. Reformers saw themselves as advocates of merit hiring, competitive contracting and professional public administration. Before LaGuardia, New York was exclusively a machine politics town. 

            The reformers had supporting them an array of political and civic organizations. There were “reform” as well as “organization” neighborhood political clubs that gathered nominating petitions and supported their own candidates in elections. But also, importantly, there was a range of “good government” civic organization, the boards of which were dominated by the city’s commercial and social elite, like the City Club, the Women’s City Club, the Municipal Art Society, the Regional Plan Association and the Citizens Budget Commission, among a dozen others, that advocated for merit hiring, competitive bidding of contracts and high-quality service delivery of government programs. [It is interesting to note that among the most high-profile reformers of the first half of the 20th Century, at least at the beginning of his career, was Yale graduate, Robert Moses]. There was a kind of yin and yang between machine and reform control of city government throughout the second half of the 20th Century in mayoral elections. The electorate went back and forth between choosing mayoral reformers and organization candidates. 

However, this began to break down with the election of the city’s first Black mayor, David Dinkins, who came up through a parallel Black political organization – and was not part of the conventional white ethnic political clubs. With the advent of media driven mayoral campaigns, the strength of the machine and reform organizations broke down, with advertising replacing organizing in turning out the vote. While many of mayor Michael Bloomberg’s initiatives mirrored the priorities of earlier reformers, he was independent of political organizations (in part because he was able to finance his own campaigns) and didn’t come out of reform political clubs (and ran as a Republican, as did Lindsey). But Rudolph Giuliani and Bill DeBlasio and would be difficult to locate on a machine/reform scale.

            Our current mayor, Eric Adams is a product of a multi-racial Brooklyn old style political machine which has continued to function into the 21st Century. He is also, importantly, a former city employee and union member. But significantly, there is no reform counterbalance to his old school political policies. Like previous machine operatives he places loyalty and ethnic politics ahead of reform type of “professional” government. An interesting argument that Mayor Adams occasionally makes is that there isn’t much evidence that “professionally” managed government was actually more responsive to local communities or delivered better services than did community embedded local political club driven machines. I am unaware of anyone today, either elected officials or visible civic organizations, advocating for traditional good government policies. Criticism of Mayor Adams is either political or personal. 

Where are today’s “reformers.” There aren’t any, as far as I can see. I would argue that just about everyone involved in local government today has a vested interest in the way things are. There are no serious voices that advocate in “the public interest” in local politics. While there is an important argument that the past promoters of reform were actually advancing the interests of the white, privileged New York establishment (aka “the ruling class”), and there is nothing besides self-interest governing politics and government, I am not so totally cynical. I do believe that there is a place for merit and professionalism in public administration. This absence of activism for professional local government has created a troubling vacuum in our discussion of how local government best might function. 

            Public spirited individuals came into high profile during the city’s fiscal meltdown of the 1970’s, when people like Felix Rohatyn (an investment banker) and Richard Ravitch (a real estate developer), wealthy, white, Jewish men from prominent families, pretty clearly selflessly got involved in attempting to rescue city government from bankruptcy – with not much in it materially for them. They were willing to take the risk of the possibility of failure and diminished reputations. They were prepared and able to speak truth to power. At that time there were other high-profile leaders who were in it to advance themselves, and who were, by contrast obsequious to power. But there were also a number of individuals who, in my judgement, were selfless and brave in their efforts. Perhaps that’s a difficult distinction to draw, or even bad form to do so, but after decades of work in and around city government, I think I’m in a position to make such an important judgment fairly – between the good guys and the bad guys.  I would venture to say that there isn’t anyone around today who could or would want to play that “good guy” role. 

            Some of this lack of civic leadership has to do with corporate globalization, which has produced business managers who tend not to feel a connection with any particular place. Just for example, while Chase Bank is headquartered in New York, I suspect its CEO, Jamie Dimon, would likely tell you that he is a citizen of the world, and is concerned with national and international issues affecting the bank. This is in contrast to David Rockefeller, a previous Chase CEO (although it was at the time a much more local and smaller enterprise) who was in the 60’s and 70’s active in New York affairs and founded the civic organization, The New York City Partnership. The leaders of the two great New York City universities also, I would guess, regard themselves as world citizens, and likely couldn’t name the Borough President of Manhattan. There are some people today who style themselves as local civic leaders, but I can’t think of one who isn’t using the public sphere to attract attention to themselves, is concerned about staying on the good side of the powerful and seeks principally to advance their personal or institutional interests through their civic involvement. They all have an agenda. They aren’t Rohatyn or Ravitch.

In the past, the boards of civic organizations were very much a creature of the business and institutional elite. Their leadership were personally and financially independent of city government and in a position to be critical of its operations. I might note that I believe essential to being able to play the role of independent public citizen is/was a certain amount of independent wealth. One needs to be in a position to not care about what powerful people in government and the media think about you. 

Today, strikingly, the boards of those organizations, while they include a few corporate leaders, have a disproportionate share of lobbyists who very much have a stake in the status quo, and not running afoul of those in power locally, who are the object of their lobbying on behalf of various commercial interests. For example, the highest profile civic organization in New York today is probably the Citizens Budget Commission – which sets itself out as a private sector monitor of the city’s fiscal probity. My recollection is that in the 1990’s its board was composed of representatives of entities with a stake in the business of municipal finance, investment banks and law firms. They had an interest in the fiscal integrity of local government, particularly as an issuer of tax-exempt debt. Today the chair of the CBC is a corporate lobbyist, and I count 11 other such lobbyists on the organization’s board. Because of the nature of lobbying, staying on the good side of elected officials is essential to the business. The same is true in the real estate industry, which is deeply reliant on local government and has about 26 members on the CBC board. It seems unlikely that CBC can be effectively critical of government operations given its governance.

It is worth noting, though, that recently, when Mayor Adams thought that the city was likely to face a serious shortfall of revenues, his first impulse to cut the budget in order to get it into balance. This was not how Mayors Lindsay and Beame operated (that is, deficit spending was seen as a legitimate policy) – and mayoral fealty to balanced budgets is a significant advance in the institutional culture of local government. 

Some of the retreat of civic organizations from controversy also has to do with the twelve years of Mayor Bloomberg’s time in City Hall. Mayor Bloomberg came from the business and social world of the boards of civic and cultural organizations – and, importantly, he shared their values of merit-based, data-driven public administration. As a result, the boards of those groups were made up of many friends and social acquaintances of Mayor Bloomberg and were loath to criticize him. This was most visibly true of the Municipal Art Society, which prior to the Bloomberg administration, had been in the business of suing city government when municipal actions were at odds with its advocacy of good public design, intelligent zoning, and historic preservation. MAS fired its in house attorney and dissolved its law committee early on in Bloomberg’s tenure are mayor. 

Now, when we have returned to a form of machine politics, there seem to be no prestigious voices articulating the public interest – no contemporary analog to Rohatyn and Ravitch. The city’s personnel and procurement systems are highly dysfunctional. There is no powerful group with the ability and interest in identifying those problems and offering solutions that would require a major overhaul of local government (structural challenges that Mayor Bloomberg, who was professionally ideally suited to address, may have chosen not to take on because they appeared so intractable to him and his team. Bloomberg seemed to be focused on addressing problems he was confident his team could solve during a mayor’s ordinary tenure). The groups that now exist on the public scene have extremely narrow agendas, like the present incarnation of the City Club, which is anti-development and anti-institutional and is exclusively involved with using litigation as a tool to advance its positions.

The diminishment of local press coverage is also a part of the problem. The New York Times, long a bastion of local good government opinion articles, also sees itself playing on a world stage. Most of its voices on local issues have narrow, “progressive” agendas. Certainly, there is no one at the Times with any knowledge (or interest) of the nitty gritty of how local government operates. The Post isn’t a serious newspaper, as actual facts seem to not be a priority in its reporting.  The Daily News is both resource constrained and consumed with mayhem and scandal. NY1 relies on a coterie of New York City lobbyists with vested interests to offer opinions on local politics and is oriented towards personalities and horse races. There are a number of independent websites now covering local government in a sophisticated way, like The City and Gothamist. But they have a limited audiences and even more limited resources. 

The worst part of this situation is that I don’t see a solution. Almost everyone who cares about New York City government today is someone who has an interest in it and doesn’t want to antagonize it. One of the things I learned mid-career is when there is government dysfunction it is not because public officials are incompetent, it is because those systems are the way they are because it is in someone’s interest for them to be that way. There is always someone or an interest group to oppose almost any change in the status quo. Those who don’t have a direct interest, aren’t interested. 

CONVENTIO ET MODUS VINCUNT LEGEM

Cities buy a lot of stuff. In Fiscal Year 2020, New York City spent almost $50 billion in what is called by its budget experts “other than personal services,” most of which is stuff: vehicles, office furniture, computers, software, pencils, envelopes, etc. In some categories, the City of New York is a likely top U.S. customer by dollar volume. We were surprised (and pleased) to find on our first day in City government, a bountiful package of office goodies on our desk; the usual stuff; pads, pens, staples, paper clips, a pair of scissors. An iPhone, iPad and MacBook, a second giant computer monitor were all centrally procured and supplied in some cases after being requested, in some cases not (the second screen, the iPad). 

Getting other stuff was not so easy. Our group’s electric vehicles all had over 100,000 miles on them. When we complained, we got banged up replacement vehicles with over 80,000 miles on them and were told that we should be delighted. Someone, we suppose got new vehicles, but it wasn’t us. The data bases our group used were over twenty years old and ran on twenty-year-old servers – which during our tenure stopped being supported. The process of replacing them took years, and persistent lobbying of both our superiors and agency budget folks. One replacement application had been in development with internal City personnel for years without progress. We eventually procured replacement software from an outside supplier, which took years to get funded, purchased and implemented. Later, another, different, data base was developed internally for our group, by a different internal team, took two years to code and another year to implement – which, by City standards, was like lightening (to its great credit, the internally coded application was excellent). 

The City’s contracting and procurement processes are designed to prevent the constant government plagues of fraud and graft. There are many historic examples of gross malfeasance in City purchasing, with William Marcy “Boss” Tweed (https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/William_M._Tweed) and the Tweed Courthouse (https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Tweed_Courthouse) as, probably, the most high profile examples. Without net profit as a metric to determine efficiency as in the private sector, the City is forced to replace it with layers and layers of process to make certain that no one is being personally benefitted from City purchases and that the City is getting the best products at the best prices from its contracting and procurement processes. The system also attempts to ensure that the City has adequate remedies when products fail and services are inadequate. There are hundreds of people employed by the City to monitor this – each with his or her own narrow list of boxes to check-off as contracts go through the system.

Outside of the City’s Office of Management and Budget (which allocates resources), and Office of Citywide Administrative Services (which includes the City’s central purchasing arm) there is a large Mayor’s Office of Contract Services that oversees this system. Unfortunately, while the system may protect the City from fraud and graft, it results in its own serious inefficiencies and failures. In our judgement, the most obvious problem with the system is that too many hands are required to touch each contract and procurement: there are too many steps as a result of the many checks involved in approving each contract. We would guess that this comes from accretion. Each time a new scandal has erupted out of a city contract gone bad, the City Council has risen to the occasion, and added a new layer of protection, which has increased the amount of oversight and the number of people who review each procurement. The result is a complex and lengthy process, with a long series of hurdles and no one looking at the big picture of whether the thing being bought is actually the best thing at the best price. 

We were recently involved in the procuring of a service, which highlighted the function’s dysfunction. In order to expedite the procurement, it was decided to utilize existing contracts with providers of that kind of service. Theoretically, therefore, these contracts had already been vetted with respect to pricing by a prior solicitation process. But this was entirely theoretical, as what was being purchased was an entirely new, and a somewhat unique service. Because only companies with existing contracts could be considered, this limited the procurement to three entities. Only two of those companies bid on the contract. The two bids were in the high six and low seven figures — $500,000 apart. It seemed like a lot to us, given the service being requested. The proposal accompanying the higher bid was clearly superior. When we spoke with a colleague involved in the procurement about the magnitude of the higher bid they shrugged it off as being about what they expected, and certainly within the “available” funds. A negotiation then took place to render the vendor’s “best and final offer” (called a BAFO). The company automatically knocked ten percent off the bid price. There was no detailed discussion about the hourly fees being charged, or the number of hours the company claimed were required for the job. As the contract was being drawn up and awarded, we discovered that, in fact, there was “no money left in the contract” with this vendor, and the process for having more funds budgeted for the company would take an additional nine months. Then, all of a sudden, for reasons that were something of a mystery to us, the procurement became a priority, the funds were appropriated and approved by OMB, and the contract was able to proceed. The basis for the end run around the procurement process, turned out to be false, but a workaround was found to the problem – creating an end run around the end run. We can’t imagine that this is what the drafters of the City Charter had in mind to protect the public fisc.

We might also note that the vendor is a large, national firm, the principals of which no doubt earn at least high six figure incomes – which the City is likely supporting through this contract – probably not through the hourly rates being charged (which seemed reasonable for the services being provided), but through the inflated number of hours quoted in the proposal/contract. This is a considerable problem facing City purchasing, put in highest relief by social service contractors, the CEO’s of which often receive compensation much greater than that of civil servants, even the Mayor. At one such agency, with nearly a $100 million in government contracts and very little other revenue, the top executive is paid around $400,000. 

There are many steps to the getting of stuff in City government. After a relatively short time (less than a decade) within the bureaucracy, we are a novice at how this all works – and we are sure that there is much more detail than we are able to identify. First, funds must be secured. A request from the lower orders has to make its way up the chain of supervision to the top of an agency – generally to its Chief Financial Officer and Commissioner (this is true, no matter the size of the request). Most requests die on the way up, or at the end – being determined to be unimportant relative to other priorities. If a request survives that gauntlet, it then goes to the agency’s budget staff to package up properly and send to OMB for view. The City’s budget agency wields tremendous power. It is responsible for making sure that at the end of each fiscal year the City has only spent what has taken in in revenue. It does this, in part, by turning down most agency requests (this is, in part, in order to make room for the Mayor’s new requests, which, obviously, take priority). Given the scale and scope of City government, and its many moving parts, this is a herculean task. Requests can languish indefinitely at OMB, without actually being turned down. Those requests that are approved by OMB return to the agency’s budget staff for procurement. 

Procurement is a highly formalized process involving the announcement of the purchase in the City Record (a daily publication of the City containing its formal legal announcements of hearings, new rules and purchases), and the solicitation of bids from vendors. In general, the lowest bid from a “responsible” bidder is required to be selected. The system has tried to bleed as much discretion out of this process as possible, in order to eliminate the possibility of malfeasance. This creates its own set of problems – because the quality of the product or service of the lowest bidder is often suspect, and the definition of “responsibility” has to do mostly with prior performance on City contracts (this isn’t much of a metric since, as we’ve previously discussed, contract terms are rarely enforced, and poor performance is often excused) and involvement in the criminal justice system. In order to prevent illicit interference with the system, agency staff’s hands are very much tied. 

We experienced this problem first hand outside of government when dealing with a huge social service provider which had been selected for a homeless services contract based on a low bid. The provider’s facility had serious negative external effects on the adjacent neighborhood.  When we met with provider’s representative, they pled lack of resources as a reason for the bad situation. It was clear to us that the provider had procured low quality security services and didn’t have enough professional staff to adequately manage the facility. We were surprised to learn after doing a little research that the provider had hundreds of millions of dollars in City contracts. We assumed this was because they were the low bidder on these procurements. But for the City to consider the quality of services being offered in selecting an operator for a facility for the homeless would be to require some civil servant to exercise some level of discretion. How to avoid favoritism, ensure quality service provision, and not be overcharged for the service being offered is a conundrum. We would err on the side of permitting the injection of some amount of judgement as to the quality of the services being provided to be included in the process. 

It is interesting to note, as a side matter, that lobbyists and prospective vendors were often asking to meet with us and our superiors to promote their products and services. This is a lot of what lobbyists seem to do – secure meetings for vendors with City officials. We couldn’t figure out why this might be the case since the procurement process was so severely constrained. Did those companies know something we didn’t know? Quite possibly. But if there was some benefit to the vendors from these meetings, the substance of that benefit was above our pay grade. If more discretion were allowed in the decision making over purchases, such meetings would be problematic unless highly structured by appropriate rules. 

Once a contract has been awarded to a vendor, a contract generally has to be drawn up, and we have discussed at some length the many attorneys who get involved in contract drafting and the results from that process. We will decline the pleasure of repeating that analysis. A contract having been agreed to, then the many hands again start to touch it. The vendor must enter its information into the City’s complex PASSPort system, the purpose of which is to weed out “irresponsible” vendors. The system keeps track of companies that owe the City money (in the form of taxes or fines) or that have defaulted on prior city engagements. The contract is then reviewed by the staff at MOCS. It is their job to make sure that all the required boxes have been checked – including whether the bidding process has been done properly, whether the procurement has land use or environmental implications (requiring an additional year-long land use review) and whether PASSPort has approved the contract. Upon MOCS’ approval, the contract then goes to the Office of the City Comptroller for what is called “registration.” Registration is essential, because it is the prerequisite to a company’s actually being able to submit a bill and be paid for the product or service it is providing for the City. Generally, the Comptroller’s review is pro forma, and if thirty days go by after a contract has been sent to the Comptroller for review and the Comptroller has taken no action, the contract is deemed registered. But the Comptroller also has the right (and, perhaps, the obligation) to fully review once again whether all of the proper steps have been taken in the issuance of the contract or procurement. The entire review process generally takes six months, once a procurement has been awarded. 

Is all this process useful or necessary? In our judgement, no. A hard look is required at the many steps to attempt to eliminate as many of them as possible – particularly those that are duplicative. 

For example, the City Charter establishes an office of the Comptroller to monitor contract compliance with various processes, rules and regulations. Review by both MOCS and the Comptroller is probably duplicative. Certainly, the Mayor’s office would rather catch problems before they get to the Comptroller’s attention (the Comptroller often being a political rival of the Mayor’s), but that doesn’t seem like a valid policy reason for an additional labor intensive and time consuming process. An even more fundamental change to the system might be to push budget making authority down further into the bureaucracy – allowing operating unit heads to control their own budgets – so long as they don’t overspend them. Agencies’ have budgets, and they should be able to allocate funds within those budgets. Similarly, agency units should be given budgets and have the ability to allocate resources within them. OMB’s role should be to ensure that agencies don’t overspend those budgets – not to pre-approve every expenditure. Again, there doesn’t seem to us to be much benefit to the City for every agency expenditure to have to be individually approved by central agency budget staff. Devolving budget authority closer to those making the expenditures would like improve the quality of decision making and expedite the process. Forcing every decision through OMB and agency fiscal staff makes the existence of budgets essentially meaningless. 

Should the City bite the bullet of allowing some discretion to bureaucrats to review bids for quality, with the added risk of at best arbitrary and at worst corrupt decision making? Probably. The risk is likely worth the improvement in City functioning. We believe that the biggest obstacle to reform of this system (besides the protection of bureaucratic turf) is the fear of tabloid stories about abuse of discretion and the waste of City funds buy bureaucrats – no matter how trivial. No one wants to be accused of allowing graft of corruption occurring within their zone of responsibility. Is the system as presently structured entirely free of graft and corruption? Probably not. Would a streamlining of the process produce a material increase in malfeasance? Also, probably not. And, as we have previously mentioned, the cost of the system, is probably orders of magnitudes greater than the marginal amount that it prevents from being misspent. 

© 2024 Publius.nyc

Theme by Anders NorenUp ↑